RECHERCHE ET ANALYSE
To what extent are WTO rules relevant to trade in natural resources?
M. Melaku Desta: Charg?de cours de droit 閏onomique international et Directeur du programme de doctorat
(uniquement en anglais)
The International Economic Law and Policy Blog hosted a week-long
discussion on various legal issues related to trade in natural resources
(10-17 March 2010). The text below highlights some of the comments
posted
Sub-questions under this included: 1) To what extent are WTO rules
relevant to trade in natural resources? 2) What makes trade in natural
resources different from trade in other products? And 3) What do we mean
by trade in natural resources anyway ?i.e. at what point does a natural
resource cease to be a natural resource and become a tradable product,
and does this matter in legal terms?
1) To what extent are WTO rules relevant to trade in natural resources?
As an introduction to this discussion, it was submitted that access to
markets, reflecting producers?interests, and access to supplies,
reflecting consumers?interests, should be distinguished. Whereas the
major issue in the natural resources sector (e.g. crude oil) is access
to supplies rather than to markets, the GATT/WTO system is designed to
advance market access more than access to supplies. Therefore, the
trading system will need to undergo radical changes in order to address
issues of supply access.
The view was expressed that WTO rules on trade in goods apply to natural
resources in the sense of applying to measures that regulate natural
resources and in the same way that they apply to measures regulating
goods more generally. When natural resources are being traded (or might
potentially be traded), they are effectively treated as goods/ products,
and as a result of this, measures regulating them are subject to the
various trade-in-goods agreements set out in Annex 1A of the WTO
Agreement. This view was supported by the reference to the dictionary
definitions (i.e., Black抯 Law Dictionary, 8th ed.) defining the terms
搉atural resources? 揼oods?and 損roducts? On the basis of these
definitions, it was argued that, although 搉atural resources?are not
goods themselves, they appear to be something akin to 損otential?goods
and, therefore, fall within the scope of 揼oods? 損roducts?within the
meaning of the WTO law. Through extraction and processing, they can be
turned into goods, and can be sold as commercial products. In other
words, all natural resources fall within the ambit of the WTO regime.
This also can be confirmed by the GATT Article XX (g) exception (i.e.,
measures relating to the conservation of exhaustible natural resources),
which suggests that natural resources are generally covered by the GATT.
Goods v. Potential Goods
It was further argued that if natural resources did not fall under the GATT, it would be too difficult to draw a line between 搉atural resources?and 揼oods? 損roducts?covered by the WTO rules. In support of the above, the example of aquaculture/fish farming was illustrated, where the line between fish as a natural resource and fish as a product appears to be particularly blurry. It was suggested that with the purpose to set a general standard, the explicit line between 搉atural resources?and 揼oods? 損roducts?should be drawn in the WTO.
However, it was noted that the above view does not imply that measures regulating natural resources would necessarily violate WTO rules (e.g. a production ban on a natural resource). On the contrary, there is a good chance that even if these measures fall under WTO rules, they will not be found in violation (or will be justified by the GATT exceptions).
In relation to the above view and particularly the coverage of the GATT,
the question was raised whether the WTO scope extends as far as to
upstream measures? It was noted that if upstream measures were covered
by the GATT/WTO rules, these measures, including production bans, would
almost certainly be equivalent to export bans, and, therefore, would
prima facie constitute a violation of the GATT. Along these lines, the
following question was asked: what is the test to determine whether a
particular upstream measure in the natural resources sector is subject
to the GATT/WTO system: i.e., is it 1) whether the measure has any
impact on trade in the product downstream, or 2) is there any
requirement of direct relationship between the measure and the tradable
product?
Upstream measures v. downstream consequences
Referring to the earlier suggestion to draw a line between 搉atural
resources?and 揼oods? 損roducts?as well as the example of fish used
thereof, the GATT Report on Canada ?Herring and Salmon [BISD 35S/98,
adopted on 22.03.1988] has been recalled. In this case, both parties and
the panel appear to agree that GATT rules do not apply to any measures
restricting fish catch (i.e., upstream measures) but only to measures
restricting the export of fish after they have been caught. Further the
parallels between Canada ?Herring and Salmon and OPEC production
control measures were drawn. It was concluded that OPEC member states
appear to be in analogous position to Canada or the US in this GATT
case. The moment OPEC countries produce the crude and ban its
exportation, or make exportation conditional on any further processing
within the countries, they would be in breach of their WTO obligations.
To the extent they only restrict production, their acts remain outside
the scope of the GATT/WTO system, falling instead under the established
principle of permanent sovereignty over natural resources. In other
words, WTO law comes into play only after a given natural resource has
passed through a production process and has been converted into a
product ready for exchange and trade. If this law applies to the
pre-production stage, it is only to the extent necessary to ensure that
measures taken at that stage do not affect the competitive relationship
on the market between the products that come out of the process.
Goods v. products: are they different? Interpretation?
In regard to the question of whether a particular upstream measure in the natural resources sector is subject to the GATT/WTO system, the arguments were submitted that the title of the Annex 1A of the Marrakesh Agreement (i.e., Multilateral Agreements on Trade in Goods [emphasis added]) implicitly answers this question. In other words, any measure affecting trade in goods will fall under the GATT. Further, the analysis of what does the term 揼ood?mean under the GATT was carried out in the light of international customary rules of treaty interpretation codified by the Vienna Convention on the Law of Treaties of 1969, Articles 31 and 32 thereof. This analysis addressed the ordinary meaning and the contexts relevant to the term 揼oods? It was concluded that natural resources may be defined as goods within the meaning of the GATT as soon as they comply with the following requirements: 1) they are listed as goods in the Member States?Schedules of Concessions on goods; 2) they are tradable (i.e., they have monetary value); and 3) they have reached a level of processing specified by the HS Nomenclature in relation to specific natural-resource-based good. On the second point, it was noted that the tradability of goods should be distinguished from the tradability of production licenses, which may, inter alia, contain a state permit to explore or exploit natural resources, but do not necessarily confer possession rights over natural resources on the licensees. It was also pointed out that when analyzing the ordinary meaning of the terms, the WTO Panels/AB should not confine their inquiry only to dictionaries; the use of rulings/opinions of judges and arbitrators in other fora, such as, inter alia, the ECJ, on the basis of the right to seek information set out in the DSU Article 13.1 was suggested.
Following up on the above arguments, the attention was drawn to the fact that the term used in the GATT Articles I, III and XI is actually 損roduct?and not 揼oods? It was noted that while both terms may have the same meaning, the starting point of the analysis should be the words actually used in the provisions at issue. The use of the term 損roduct? in the above provisions appears to create additional limitations on their application to natural resources. In addition, the question was raised whether the GATT Article XXIII: 1 (b) is limited only to products, or not? The other point brought up along the same lines was that the GATT Articles I, III and XI do not apply to every measure 揳ffecting?products, but rather, each of them establishes the degree of connection required between a measure and a product, narrowing the broader term 揳ffecting?in some way or another.
In relation to the argument that in order to be defined as goods within
the meaning of the GATT a natural resource has to be, inter alia, a
搕radable good? the US - Softwood Lumber IV case has been recalled
[WT/DS257/R; WT/DS257/AB/R adopted on 17.02.2004], where both the panel
and the Appellate Body rejected Canada抯 argument that the term 揼oods?
in the context of a subsidy provided in the form of goods or services
other than general infrastructure (see Article 1.1(a)(1)(iii) of the SCM
Agreement) is limited to tradable goods. This point appears to be
relevant also to the above argument that the WTO law may extend to
measures applied at pre-production stage, if these measures affect the
competitive relationship between products on the market.
Questions lead to further questions
The following further questions were raised during the discussion: 1) To what extent have countries surrendered their sovereignty over natural resources under international law? And 2) Can GATT Articles XI (i.e., General Elimination of Quantitative Restrictions) and XVII (i.e., State Trading Enterprises) be considered as an expression of state consent to limit their sovereignty over their natural resources?.