RESEARCH AND ANALYSIS
A Public Financial Management Framework for Resources-Producing Countries(1)
Teresa Dab醤 (The Western Hemisphere Department) and Jean Luc H閘is (The Fiscal Affairs Department), the International Monetary Fund (IMF)
If well-managed, resource revenues, that is the revenues that
resource-rich countries may obtain from their natural resources, could
represent a big economic opportunity, especially given the advantages
they present with respect to other government sources of financing. The
most salient advantage is that resource revenues could be considered as
a "gift from nature? in some cases generated by the discovery of a
sub-soil asset, which automatically translates into an expansion in the
country抯 gross domestic product and the government抯 financial
envelope. Another advantage is that resource revenues are not subject to
the conditions that donors and lenders usually impose on recipient
countries. A third advantage resides in the 揺nclave?nature of resource
revenues, which makes it possible that resource revenues could be
generated in extremely challenging circumstances, including in some
cases internal armed conflict. This contrasts with the collection of
non-resource revenues and borrowing, which are affected by domestic
demand conditions and countries?credit rating.
However, resource revenues also pose significant challenges, mainly in
the form of the so-called 搑esource curse敆a complex phenomenon through
which an abundance of resource revenues can translate into stagnation,
waste, corruption and conflict. The resource curse could derive from the
macroeconomic and budgetary difficulties of managing resource-related
funds, which usually are large and extremely volatile. In particular,
the most common story of resource-producing countries responds to a
cycle of high revenue/high expectations/high expenditure followed by a
resource price slump, a decline in resource revenues, and social unrest
caused by fiscal and budgetary adjustments. As a result, most
resource-producing countries tend to fall behind non-resource producing
economies in economic development, rate of growth, income per capita and
human development. In addition, the resource curse could derive from the
way in which resource revenues are generated. Because in most cases they
derive from depleting an exhaustible asset and can be generated without
the direct scrutiny of taxpayers, donors, and lenders, resource revenues
usually pose important intergenerational, political economy and
governance challenges. In particular, resource-producing countries are
relatively prone to develop a 搑entier?mentality and experience armed
civil conflict.
But the resource curse is not an 搃ron law?(Auty, 1994), but a disease
that can be prevented with the implementation of the right policy
prescriptions. These policy prescriptions include the implementation of
prudent macroeconomic policies, the adoption of a sound strategy to
promote development and economic diversification, and the enhancement of
the country抯 institutional framework, including the public financial
management (PFM) system. Moreover, country experience shows that the
success on preventing the resource curse depends on countries?
pre-existing conditions and institutions before that resource revenues
came into stream. In fact, most developed resource-producing countries
(such as Norway, Chile, Australia, or Canada among other) usually had a
sound governance system prior to the resource era, and therefore were
better equipped to implement the policy prescriptions to prevent the
resource curse. However, low-income resource-producing countries, which
usually have adverse pre-existing institutional conditions, are more
prone to fail in adopting the right policies and preventing the resource
curse
Cross-country experience also shows that some resource-producing
countries have resorted to special mechanisms to manage their resource
revenues, with a view to bypassing their ill-functioning PFM systems.
The most used mechanisms include special arrangements for the allocation
and use of resource revenues, the creation of resource funds, the
adoption of 損arallel?budgetary and treasury procedures, the creation
of separate investment committees and oversight institutions, and the
enactment of special legal frameworks. Three rationales are usually put
forward to justify the adoption of these special mechanisms: (i) the
convenience of mobilizing public support for managing resource revenues
in a special and reinforced way, even in countries with acceptable
institutional frameworks; (ii) the need to overcome the weaknesses of
the existing PFM systems, by implementing quickly certain parallel
mechanisms, given that reforms are likely to take time; and, (iii) the
expediency of carving out a space within the public sector in which the
appropriate budgetary mechanisms and transparency standards can be put
to work in a highly visible.
In a few cases, such as Chile and Norway, the adoption of these special
mechanisms has been successful. However, country experience shows that
the design and implementation of these mechanisms have in general posed
significant challenges, especially to less-developed countries. In fact,
when designed in a non-transparent and rigid way, these mechanisms may
have contributed to the failure of some resource-producing countries in
preventing the resource curse. The parallel mechanisms have in some
cases: (i) increased opportunities for misappropriation and
mismanagement, especially in countries with a high concentration of
power; (ii) led to the fragmentation and delay of the budget process,
especially in countries with poor sharing-information practices; (iii)
resulted in high administrative costs, reflecting the differentiated,
expensive, and sometime privileged bureaucracy of the parallel bodies;
and (iv) discouraged the incentive for reforming existing budgetary
institutions and building an efficient and merit-based civil service.
Against this background, resource-producing countries should adopt a PFM
framework that enhances, instead of replacing, existing budgetary
institutions and preserve the integrity of the budget process. A PFM for
resource-producing countries should include: (i) a transparent and
comprehensive presentation of resource revenue in the budget梕mphasizing
the role of the non-resource deficit; (ii) a set of sound long-term
projections, a sustainable long-term fiscal strategy, and realistic
medium-term fiscal frameworks; (iii) a set of well-defined budget
classifications to track budget execution; (iv) a system of flexible and
transparent transfers from the treasury accounts to finance the
non-resource budget deficit; (v) the development of an unified budget
execution process, avoiding rigid and non-transparent earmarking
mechanisms; (vi) sound cash flow and asset-liability management, based
on a simple and integrated banking circuit and integrated treasury
accounts; and (vii) enhanced accountability and transparency mechanisms.
The adoption of such a PFM framework should be supported by a reform
path that take into account the institutional diversity of
resource-producing countries and allow for the adoption of PFM choices
that are tailored to the institutional reality of low-income countries.
In the short term, reforms should focus on adopting basic PFM tools,
while, over the medium term, reforms should aim at making the PFM
systems of low-income resource-producing countries converge with best
international practices.
References
Auty, R., 1994, 揑ndustrial Policy Reform in Six Newly Industrializing
Countries: the Resource Curse Thesis? World Development, Vol. 22, No1.
Dab醤, T and J.L. Helis 2010, 揂 Public Financial Management Framework
for Resource-Producing Countries? WP/10/72, Washington: International
Monetary Fund.