RESEARCH AND ANALYSIS
Always Look at the Bright Side of Non-Delivery: WTO and Preferential Trade Agreements, Yesterday and Today
Petros C. Mavroidis, Professor of Foreign and Comparative Law at Columbia University's Law School, and Professor Law at the University of Neuchatel
The disciplining of preferential trade agreements (PTAs) by the WTO has
been ‘relaxed’ recently as a result of the new transparency mechanism
within which notified PTAs are being multilaterally reviewed. This is
probably a blessing for a number of reasons including the success of the
multilateral trading system in bringing tariffs down over the years (and
the ensuing reduced trade diversion), the fact that modern PTAs deal
with many non-trade issues as well (for which no WTO disciplines exist),
and recent empirical literature suggesting overall positive welfare
implications for those participating in similar schemes. This paper
discusses these and other reasons to support the view that the WTO
should rather focus on the multilateral agenda instead of diverting its
attention towards disciplining PTAs. Here are a few key points:
?nbsp;
From Day One We Applied the Wrong Test
The GATT-test for consistency of PTAs with the multilateral rules aims
at ensuring that PTAs will not be ?la carte: absent the substantially
all trade-requirement, PTAs could be formed on one tariff line only.
This could severely undermine MFN, the cornerstone of the GATT-edifice.
So the GATT framers could not live with a GATT ?la carte, but could
live with GATT-consistent PTAs which resulted in trade diversion, the
evil Viner in his classic analysis warned us against. Indeed, especially
in the ‘50s and the ‘60s when MFN rates were high (and thus, the
potential margin of preference large) PTAs that would take the intra-PTA
tariff rates to 0% could create substantial trade diversion if the PTA
partners were relatively inefficient (un-competitive). The GATT would
applaud while Viner’s worst fears would have been confirmed. One might
legitimately ask the question whether the candle is indeed worth the
flame? Should we, in other words, be enforcing an economics-uninformed
test in the name of avoiding PTAs ?la carte? How realistic is this risk
anyway?
?nbsp;
What is the Counterfactual to Trade Diversion?
The classic Vinerian analysis would request us to calculate the trade
created through the establishment of a PTA (since intra-PTA trade would
be liberalized) and compare it to the trade diverted (since trade might
be deflected from the worldwide most efficient source of supply to the
intra-PTA most efficient source of supply). One of course, might cast
significant doubt on the appropriateness of such measurement, since it
assumes the counterfactual. What if countries refused to make the same
MFN cuts if they were deprived of the possibility to go preferential?
What if they refused to participate in the WTO altogether? This is not
meant to put into question the classic Vinerian analysis. Indeed, Viner
was interested in measuring the allocational impact of discriminatory
integration; the point here concerns Realpolitik and suggests that there
is no reason to believe that MFN cuts would be the appropriate
counterfactual to preferences.
?nbsp;
Is Trade Diversion an Issue as it Was?
Recent empirical studies provide us with mixed evidence regarding the
extent of trade diversion resulting from the formation of PTAs. We lack
a comprehensive calculation of trade diversion for all PTAs (indeed one
might wonder if one is feasible), but the on-going tariff liberalization
of tariffs at MFN-level would strongly argue in favour of the thesis
that the problem is not of the magnitude that it used to be.
Scholarship points to the (missing) incentives to agree on MFN tariff
cuts following establishment of a PTA. Bhagwati (2002), Krishna (1998)
and Lim鉶 (2006) all have contributed in making the point that, besides
trade diversion created through the establishment of PTAs, members of
PTAs behave as enemies of non-discriminatory trade liberalization, since
they are unwilling to cut tariffs on MFN basis for fear of eroding the
margin of preference that they have granted to their PTA-partners. They
become thus, stumbling (as opposed to building) blocs opposing MFN trade
liberalization, and frustrating the achievement of the basic WTO
objective. The fear was probably legitimate at some point, but the
question is how relevant is it today?
On the one hand studies like Karacaovali and Lim鉶 (2008) looking at the
EU, and Lim鉶 (2006) looking at the US have provided empirical evidence
that PTAs have behaved like stumbling blocs. They ask the question
whether MFN tariff cuts during the Uruguay Round are related to their
preferential tariffs. The stumbling bloc-thesis would suggest that
trading nations would have cut tariffs less in areas where they had
preferential tariffs, and indeed this what these authors finds. Other
studies however find the opposite. Estevadeordal, Freund and Ornelas
(2008) examine the Latin experience with PTAs and find that Latin
nations cut their MFN rates most in products where they had preferences
in place. Baldwin and Seghezza (2010) use tariff data for 23 large
trading nations and find that MFN cuts and preferences are complements
not substitutes: preferences tend be zero or close to zero where nations
have high MFN tariffs. Intuitively, one would associate the stumbling
bloc thesis with large preferences in similar cases, but the authors
show that this is not the case. The authors discard thus, the stumbling
bloc- without supporting the building bloc thesis. Acharya et al. (2011)
in similar vein, find that the impact of plurilateral PTAs on extra-PTA
imports and exports is large and positive. If at all, recent empirical
evidence hardly supports the uni-dimensional conclusion that PTAs are
stumbling blocs per se.
Of course trade diversion can result from instruments other than
tariffs. It can result from say convergent environmental or public
health policies across PTA partners. With respect to domestic
instruments in general, nonetheless, there is no need for action: to the
extent that a trade advantage has been conferred, it must be extended to
all WTO Members automatically and unconditionally by virtue of Art. I
GATT (MFN). PTAs in other words, cannot provide legal shelter for
discriminatory domestic instruments since the latter were not meant to
protect anyway, and hence, cannot be regarded as a restrictive
regulation of commerce in the sense of the term embedded in Art. XXIV
GATT.
Trade diversion can also result from say increased use of antidumping
(AD) proceedings against non PTA partners, as the work of Prusa and Teh
(2010) shows. Once again though, nothing much can be done about it: at a
positive level, the only MFN obligation that WTO Members incur with
respect to AD duties is to collect them on non-discriminatory basis; at
a normative level, the burden associated with proving that under similar
circumstances PTA partners privileged AD proceedings against a sub-set
of the WTO Membership (namely, outsiders to their PTA) is quite high:
except for conceptual issues, those carrying the burden of proof (that
is, the Members asked to pay them) will have to also address issues such
as opportunity cost of conducting another investigation, scarcity of
administrative resources etc.
Concluding remarks
PTAs are formed for many, often idiosyncratic
reasons. We cited some of the reasons and there are many more. Baldwin
(1997), for example, tries to explore the validity of some of the
rationales, and, more recently, Whalley (2008) attempts a similar
endeavour. Some of the rationales advanced have even (persuasively)
criticized. For example, the argument has time and again been advanced
(and continues to do so) that countries have gone preferential because
they were frustrated with the slow pace of multilateral tariff
liberalization. I attach little value to this view. If true, then why
did not they go for what Bhagwati has termed open regionalism, that is
allow others to join their PTA assuming they had agreed on the tariff
cuts decided? Other rationales hold more promise. Baldwin (2008), for
example, develops a theory aiming to predict who goes preferential
depending on the identity of the spoke and the hub that have already
gone preferential. But we lack a dominant explanation that can serve as
rationale across PTAs. This observation in and of itself would cast
severe doubt on remedial action against PTAs since it is questionable
whether the same remedy should apply to divergent situations.
The historic rationale for PTAs is of no much help either. Arguably, one
reason for its inclusion is that the GATT negotiators were presented
with a fait accompli. Two CU participated in the negotiation, the Syro-Lebanese
customs union (Syria, Lebanon), and Benelux (Belgium, Netherlands,
Luxembourg). Institutional arrangements probably had to be made in order
to accommodate these contracting parties. Chase (2006) drawing from a
series of archival records, begs to differ and points to a different
direction: the author persuasively demonstrates that it was the US
negotiators that designed this provision in order to accommodate a trade
agreement that they had secretly reached with Canada. The US – Canada
FTA did not see the light of the day then but only 40 years later. On
the other hand, the view held by many that the inclusion of a provision
on FTAs was there to accommodate the European integration process must
be discarded. In Acheson’s (1969) record, Jean Monnet revealed his plans
on European integration after the Havana Conference had taken place.
We are still struggling with the rationale but recent research paints a
much rosier picture for PTAs than what was the case before. One
contributing factor is the success of the multilateral trading system.
MFN reduction of tariffs results in reduction of trade diversion created
through PTAs. So we are now facing a problem less acute than before.
Moreover, the content of PTAs has changed drastically over the recent
years and moved to areas escaping the current WTO mandate. Finally,
empirical evidence shows that PTAs can be welfare improving. And while
all these changes were happening, the WTO continued to enforce an
ill-informed and out-dated to constrain PTAs. Against this background,
the shift towards a mere exercise in transparency (facilitated by the
WTO Transparency Mechanism) should be welcome with relief. If at all, it
removes the risk for false positives which can have important
institutional (negative) external effects.
Petros C. Mavroidis is the Edwin B. Parker Professor of Foreign and Comparative Law at Columbia University's Law School, and Professor Law at the University of Neuchatel. Prof. Mavroidis has written extensively on the WTO and its predecessor, GATT. He is also involved with the American Law Institute as a chief co-reporter on the principles of WTO law.